Improving the Affordable Care Act Markets (Part 2)

By | October 25, 2019

By JONATHAN HALVORSON

In a previous post, I described how some features of the Affordable Care Act, despite the best intentions, have made it harder or even impossible for many plans to compete against dominant players in the individual and small employer markets. This has undermined aspects of the ACA designed to improve competition, like the insurance exchanges, and exacerbated a long term trend toward consolidation and reduced choice, and there is evidence it is resulting in higher costs. I focused on the ACA’s risk adjustment program and its impact on the small group market where the damage has been greatest.

The goal of risk adjustment is commendable: to create stability and fairness by removing the ability of plans to profit by “cherry picking” healthier enrollees, so that plans instead compete on innovative services, disease management, administrative efficiency, and customer support. But in the attempt to find stability, the playing field was tilted in favor of plans with long-tenured enrollment and sophisticated operations to identify all scorable health risks. The next generation of risk adjustment should truly even out the playing field by retaining the current program’s elimination of an incentive to avoid the sick, while also eliminating its bias towards incumbency and other unintended effects.

One important distinction concerns when to use risk adjustment to balance out differences that arise from consumer preferences. For example, high deductible plans tend to attract healthier enrollees, and without risk adjustment these plans would become even cheaper than they already are, while more comprehensive plans that attract sicker members would get disproportionately more expensive, setting off a race to the bottom that pushes more and more people into the plans that have the least benefits, while the sickest stay behind in more generous plans whose premium cost spirals upward. Using risk adjustment to counteract this effect has been widely beneficial in the individual market, along with other features like community rating and guaranteed issue.

Read More:  Common hypertension medications may reduce colorectal cancer risk

However, in other cases where risk levels between plans differ due to consumer preferences it may not be helpful. For example, it has been documented that older and sicker members have a greater aversion to change (changing plans to something less familiar) and to constraints intended to lower cost even if they do not undermine benefit levels or quality of care, like narrow networks. These aversions tend to make newer plans and small network plans score as healthier. Risk adjustment would then force those plans to pay a penalty that in turn forces enrollees in the plans to pay for the preferences of others.

If new plans, or innovations to control costs and avoid over-utilization such as narrow networks and tiered pharmacies were not in the public interest, then those penalties could be justified. But since the ACA relies on contracting strategies available to private plans (not rate setting) to control costs, penalizing such innovations through risk adjustment will undermine competition and efforts at cost control. These constraints may also actually improve the quality of care and quality of life by avoiding unnecessary care and the complications it can create, and better coordinating care among more integrated providers. There is evidence in Massachusetts and elsewhere that risk adjustment penalties due to these preferences harm the public interest.

A small insurer that contracts with the same providers as a large one is going to pay more for each service provided, especially at hospital systems and medical groups that have a strong position when negotiating rates. A careful analysis of the New York market found that this was likely the single largest driver of losses among start-up health plans, but the risk adjustment model makes no accommodation for it. The only way for a smaller plan to partially counteract this large plan cost advantage is to have a more narrow network and form a close alliance with a limited number of provider partners. In doing so, that insurer will exclude some important institutions in the local area, and people who are least amendable to this tend to be older and sicker. The risk adjustment model makes no allowance for this selection preference.

Read More:  How to make viagra home

The increased willingness of younger and heathier people (and small businesses) to try something new could help mitigate the benefits of size and incumbency, but the current risk adjustment model throws up roadblocks to this opening for innovation.

The measurement methodology itself also creates issues. As mentioned in my previous post, inevitably a dominant insurer will pull the average statewide risk score to be closer to its level than competitors, and what can seem like a small payment to it is huge to its competitors as a share of their premium. The largest incumbent plans also have a lot of historical data needed to effectively confirm each year what conditions (scorable risks) its members have, and sophisticated operations to find and confirm new diagnoses every year, as the ACA requires. This results in plans receiving higher risk scores than others that do not reflect true underlying differences in risk.

So, what can be done? Below are three suggestions for further discussion:

  • Add Value Control Factor – A Value Control factor could be established for select innovations that address cost and quality but may be selected against by enrollees with higher costs. Such factors could include small integrated networks, restriction to in-network benefits, reliance on a PCP to coordinate care, and tiered formularies. The amount of any risk transfer payments from a plan with eligible cost/quality controls could be reduced by this factor, in order to reduce penalties for innovative solutions that align incentives more closely between payers and providers, avoid waste and inflation, and improve collaboration in care management. This factor would be empirically established in each state, and if there is no measured impact then no factor would be applied. Plan designs that simply increase member cost-sharing would not be eligible for a Value Control factor.
  • Provide Relief for Small Plans – If a plan in a highly concentrated insurance market has less than a certain market share (e.g., 5%), it should be allowed relief from some of the burden of risk adjustment transfers. Plans could be made to opt-in to this program in advance to avoid gaming, and market share should be set at the level of the insurer in a particular market (namely the individual or small group market) rather than a specific insurance product. This relief is necessary to counter some of the advantages larger plans typically have from their long-tenured membership, favorable contracted rates with providers, and close relationships with brokers who steer coverage decisions.
Read More:  Americans Skip Meds and Borrow Billions to Pay for Basic Health Care

The ACA has done well given the limitations it has faced. Millions more Americans have insurance than before, and those with existing health conditions are freed from the fear of being rejected for coverage simply because they are sick. Even under an administration hostile to it, enrollment has been stable for those receiving subsidies on the exchanges. However, the unsubsidized individual market and the small group market have been shrinking, while the dominant insurers keep getting more dominant. We face the prospect of stagnant marketplaces with shrinking competition, higher premiums and fewer enrollees. HHS has repeatedly invited states to submit their own proposals for alterations to the federal risk adjustment program to suit the conditions of each state, though so far only Alabama (in 2018) and New York (in 2017, as an emergency measure) have done so. It is better late than never for states to take HHS up on its offer.

Jonathan Halvorson is a Senior Healthcare Consultant at Sachs Policy Group and has a long-term interest in the transformative potential of technology on the health care system

Livongo’s Post Ad Banner 728*90

The Health Care Blog